Changing Rules for Regulation of Icelandic Fisheries

The diplomatic corps of Iceland has used much of its time during the third quarter of the 20. century to convince other nations that Icelanders should control and utilise the resources of the waters within 12, then 50 and finally 200 nautical miles around the island. Icelandic politicians have used...

Full description

Bibliographic Details
Main Author: Matthíasson, Thórólfur
Other Authors: Johnston, Richard S., Shriver, Ann L.
Format: Conference Object
Language:English
unknown
Published: International Institute of Fisheries Economics and Trade
Subjects:
Online Access:https://ir.library.oregonstate.edu/concern/conference_proceedings_or_journals/dr26xz11x
id ftoregonstate:ir.library.oregonstate.edu:dr26xz11x
record_format openpolar
spelling ftoregonstate:ir.library.oregonstate.edu:dr26xz11x 2024-09-15T18:13:40+00:00 Changing Rules for Regulation of Icelandic Fisheries Matthíasson, Thórólfur Johnston, Richard S. Shriver, Ann L. https://ir.library.oregonstate.edu/concern/conference_proceedings_or_journals/dr26xz11x English [eng] eng unknown International Institute of Fisheries Economics and Trade https://ir.library.oregonstate.edu/concern/conference_proceedings_or_journals/dr26xz11x Copyright Not Evaluated Conference Proceeding ftoregonstate 2024-07-22T18:06:05Z The diplomatic corps of Iceland has used much of its time during the third quarter of the 20. century to convince other nations that Icelanders should control and utilise the resources of the waters within 12, then 50 and finally 200 nautical miles around the island. Icelandic politicians have used much of their time and effort during the fourth quarter of the 20. century to debate how to organise the utilisation of the resource and in what way one should distribute the rents from its harvesting. In the paper give a short account of the development of the regulatory reforms in four types of Icelandic fisheries. No one of the reformatory processes can be said to be a replica of the any of the other processes. It seems evident at the face of things that each reformatory process is unique and distinct from the other except for the final outcome, the rule of the ITQs. But that may seem to be to short sighted conclusion. It should be evident from the earliest history of regulatory reforms that the ITQ system was not the intentional outcome. It came to be, eventually. There is a common pattern for all the fisheries, however. First of all: The serious attempts to reform the management practise starts first when the fishery has collapsed or is close to a collapse. Secondly, the first thing that stake holders seem to get done is to close the club that has access to the given fishery. Thirdly, a variety of rules was used to allocate participation rights when the club of participants had been closed. Fourthly, prices were used to manage fisheries in Iceland prior to the invention of the ITQ system. Lastly, management of fisheries by ITQs rather than some form of taxes or fees may have historical rather than logical roots. Conference Object Iceland ScholarsArchive@OSU (Oregon State University)
institution Open Polar
collection ScholarsArchive@OSU (Oregon State University)
op_collection_id ftoregonstate
language English
unknown
description The diplomatic corps of Iceland has used much of its time during the third quarter of the 20. century to convince other nations that Icelanders should control and utilise the resources of the waters within 12, then 50 and finally 200 nautical miles around the island. Icelandic politicians have used much of their time and effort during the fourth quarter of the 20. century to debate how to organise the utilisation of the resource and in what way one should distribute the rents from its harvesting. In the paper give a short account of the development of the regulatory reforms in four types of Icelandic fisheries. No one of the reformatory processes can be said to be a replica of the any of the other processes. It seems evident at the face of things that each reformatory process is unique and distinct from the other except for the final outcome, the rule of the ITQs. But that may seem to be to short sighted conclusion. It should be evident from the earliest history of regulatory reforms that the ITQ system was not the intentional outcome. It came to be, eventually. There is a common pattern for all the fisheries, however. First of all: The serious attempts to reform the management practise starts first when the fishery has collapsed or is close to a collapse. Secondly, the first thing that stake holders seem to get done is to close the club that has access to the given fishery. Thirdly, a variety of rules was used to allocate participation rights when the club of participants had been closed. Fourthly, prices were used to manage fisheries in Iceland prior to the invention of the ITQ system. Lastly, management of fisheries by ITQs rather than some form of taxes or fees may have historical rather than logical roots.
author2 Johnston, Richard S.
Shriver, Ann L.
format Conference Object
author Matthíasson, Thórólfur
spellingShingle Matthíasson, Thórólfur
Changing Rules for Regulation of Icelandic Fisheries
author_facet Matthíasson, Thórólfur
author_sort Matthíasson, Thórólfur
title Changing Rules for Regulation of Icelandic Fisheries
title_short Changing Rules for Regulation of Icelandic Fisheries
title_full Changing Rules for Regulation of Icelandic Fisheries
title_fullStr Changing Rules for Regulation of Icelandic Fisheries
title_full_unstemmed Changing Rules for Regulation of Icelandic Fisheries
title_sort changing rules for regulation of icelandic fisheries
publisher International Institute of Fisheries Economics and Trade
url https://ir.library.oregonstate.edu/concern/conference_proceedings_or_journals/dr26xz11x
genre Iceland
genre_facet Iceland
op_relation https://ir.library.oregonstate.edu/concern/conference_proceedings_or_journals/dr26xz11x
op_rights Copyright Not Evaluated
_version_ 1810451431344308224