Paying a Premium for “Green Steel”: Paying for an Illusion?

Abstract The iron and steel industry generates around 10 % of global greenhouse gas emissions. The bulk of the emissions originates from the iron ore reduction. In this reduction, coal is used as a reagent. Steelmakers could switch to hydrogen-based direct reduction using hydrogen instead of coal as...

Full description

Bibliographic Details
Published in:Journal of Benefit-Cost Analysis
Main Authors: Johansson, Per-Olov, Kriström, Bengt
Format: Article in Journal/Newspaper
Language:English
Published: Cambridge University Press (CUP) 2022
Subjects:
Online Access:http://dx.doi.org/10.1017/bca.2022.20
https://www.cambridge.org/core/services/aop-cambridge-core/content/view/S2194588822000203
id crcambridgeupr:10.1017/bca.2022.20
record_format openpolar
spelling crcambridgeupr:10.1017/bca.2022.20 2024-06-09T07:48:37+00:00 Paying a Premium for “Green Steel”: Paying for an Illusion? Johansson, Per-Olov Kriström, Bengt 2022 http://dx.doi.org/10.1017/bca.2022.20 https://www.cambridge.org/core/services/aop-cambridge-core/content/view/S2194588822000203 en eng Cambridge University Press (CUP) http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0 Journal of Benefit-Cost Analysis volume 13, issue 3, page 383-393 ISSN 2194-5888 2152-2812 journal-article 2022 crcambridgeupr https://doi.org/10.1017/bca.2022.20 2024-05-15T13:15:12Z Abstract The iron and steel industry generates around 10 % of global greenhouse gas emissions. The bulk of the emissions originates from the iron ore reduction. In this reduction, coal is used as a reagent. Steelmakers could switch to hydrogen-based direct reduction using hydrogen instead of coal as a reagent to reduce iron ore to pig iron. This would eliminate the CO 2 emissions from the equivalent process in a traditional blast furnace. However, the process requires massive amounts of electricity. This paper looks at the economics of such a switch to “green steel.” We assess a marginal increase in the production of a hypothetical green steelmaker. We also undertake an investment appraisal of a green plant, based on an ongoing installation in Northern Sweden, but also briefly consider a possible/planned investment in the US. This appraisal is complemented by computing the survival function for the net present value in a systematic sensitivity analysis. It seems highly unlikely that a green steel plant can be socially profitable. If the green plant displaces conventional steel produced within the European Union’s cap-and-trade system for greenhouse gases, total emissions remain more or less unaffected; permits and emissions are simply reshuffled. Hence, if end-users of green steel pay a premium, they might pay for an illusion. Article in Journal/Newspaper Northern Sweden Cambridge University Press Journal of Benefit-Cost Analysis 1 11
institution Open Polar
collection Cambridge University Press
op_collection_id crcambridgeupr
language English
description Abstract The iron and steel industry generates around 10 % of global greenhouse gas emissions. The bulk of the emissions originates from the iron ore reduction. In this reduction, coal is used as a reagent. Steelmakers could switch to hydrogen-based direct reduction using hydrogen instead of coal as a reagent to reduce iron ore to pig iron. This would eliminate the CO 2 emissions from the equivalent process in a traditional blast furnace. However, the process requires massive amounts of electricity. This paper looks at the economics of such a switch to “green steel.” We assess a marginal increase in the production of a hypothetical green steelmaker. We also undertake an investment appraisal of a green plant, based on an ongoing installation in Northern Sweden, but also briefly consider a possible/planned investment in the US. This appraisal is complemented by computing the survival function for the net present value in a systematic sensitivity analysis. It seems highly unlikely that a green steel plant can be socially profitable. If the green plant displaces conventional steel produced within the European Union’s cap-and-trade system for greenhouse gases, total emissions remain more or less unaffected; permits and emissions are simply reshuffled. Hence, if end-users of green steel pay a premium, they might pay for an illusion.
format Article in Journal/Newspaper
author Johansson, Per-Olov
Kriström, Bengt
spellingShingle Johansson, Per-Olov
Kriström, Bengt
Paying a Premium for “Green Steel”: Paying for an Illusion?
author_facet Johansson, Per-Olov
Kriström, Bengt
author_sort Johansson, Per-Olov
title Paying a Premium for “Green Steel”: Paying for an Illusion?
title_short Paying a Premium for “Green Steel”: Paying for an Illusion?
title_full Paying a Premium for “Green Steel”: Paying for an Illusion?
title_fullStr Paying a Premium for “Green Steel”: Paying for an Illusion?
title_full_unstemmed Paying a Premium for “Green Steel”: Paying for an Illusion?
title_sort paying a premium for “green steel”: paying for an illusion?
publisher Cambridge University Press (CUP)
publishDate 2022
url http://dx.doi.org/10.1017/bca.2022.20
https://www.cambridge.org/core/services/aop-cambridge-core/content/view/S2194588822000203
genre Northern Sweden
genre_facet Northern Sweden
op_source Journal of Benefit-Cost Analysis
volume 13, issue 3, page 383-393
ISSN 2194-5888 2152-2812
op_rights http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0
op_doi https://doi.org/10.1017/bca.2022.20
container_title Journal of Benefit-Cost Analysis
container_start_page 1
op_container_end_page 11
_version_ 1801380392412905472